Providing Prescription Drug Coverage to the Elderly: America’s Experiment with Medicare Part D
Mark Duggan, Patrick Healy, and Fiona Scott Morton
Mark Duggan is Professor of Economics, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland. Patrick Healy is a Senior Research Assistant, Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C. Fiona Scott Morton is Professor of Economics, Yale University, School of Management, New Haven, Connecticut. Both Duggan and Scott Morton are Research Associates, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Their email addresses are [email protected], [email protected], [email protected], respectively. Acknowledgements: We are grateful to Jim Hines, Jeremy Stein, and Tim Taylor for very helpful comments on an earlier draft. Duggan and Scott Morton also thank the National Science Foundation for supporting this research.
The share of U.S. health care spending accounted for by prescription drugs has steadily
increased since the early 1980s, from 4.5 percent in 1982 to 5.6 percent in 1994, with this then
rapidly accelerating to 10.1 percent by 2005 (CMS, 2008). However, the federal government’s
Medicare program did not provide prescription drug coverage for the first 40 years of its
existence since its inception in 1966.1 Thus, more than 30 percent of the 44 million elderly and
disabled beneficiaries of the program lacked insurance coverage for prescribed medications and
could not easily afford to pay for them out of pocket (Neuman et al., 2007).
The Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003
established a voluntary outpatient prescription drug benefit known as Medicare Part D. This
program took effect in 2006, and represents the largest expansion of an entitlement program
since the start of Medicare itself. In 2007, Part D covered 24 million beneficiaries and cost the
federal government $39 billion, for an average of $1,625 per individual enrolled. This cost is
projected to grow as per capita health care costs continue to outpace GDP growth and as the
baby boom generation ages (CBO, 2008). The Medicare Trustees (2008) estimate that by 2015,
Part D will cover 34 million Medicare recipients and will have cost the federal government a
The design of Part D is of particular interest to economists for at least three reasons.
First, the program has the potential to significantly affect both the health and the economic well-
being of the more than 44 million individuals currently enrolled in Medicare. Second, Part D has
substantially increased government spending on health care despite the projections that this
spending was already on an unsustainable path. Third, Part D represents an ambitious attempt to
use market mechanisms in the delivery of a large-scale entitlement program. Other federal
prescription drug programs have purchased drugs and dispensed them directly, like the U.S.
Department of Veterans’ Affairs, or employed a formula to determine the price to pay for each
treatment, like Medicaid (Duggan and Scott Morton, 2006). In contrast, Medicare Part D aims to
control spending by exposing its enrollees to the full incremental costs above a benchmark
insurance plan, and by allowing private insurance plans to compete for enrollees by negotiating
with drug manufacturers for lower prices and covering treatments that are valued by Medicare
recipients. These insurers, operating under substantial federal subsidies and rules to ensure
1 The one exception was for drugs administered in hospitals and other institutional settings and for selected drugs administered in physicians’ offices, primarily those for cancer therapy.
access, compete for enrollees in one or more regions based on benefit design, price, and service.
Medicare recipients can choose from among dozens of plans, potentially allowing for a better
match on average between individual preferences and services provided than one uniform
Because of this design, Part D has been controversial. One set of critics has argued that
the program is a subsidized handout to pharmaceutical firms, and that the government should
instead negotiate directly with pharmaceutical manufacturers over prices. Another set of critics
has complained that the program is too large and generous, and that it creates unnecessary
government interference in the pharmaceutical market. Still other critics claim that the profusion
of plans and options is so complex and confusing that the elderly are unable to understand their
options and make the best choice. In this paper, we aim to shed light on these and many related
issues, including the incentives inherent in the competition among plans, the forces that affect
drug prices, and the sustainability of Part D in the face of adverse selection and moral hazard.
We conclude that Part D has succeeded in a number of important ways – by on average
reducing pharmaceutical prices, increasing the utilization of prescription drugs, reducing medical
expenditure risk, and costing the government substantially less than the initial budget projections
suggested. However, the results from recent research suggest that the complexity of the program
has resulted in suboptimal choices by many Medicare recipients and that Part D has increased the
price of treatments without therapeutic substitutes (Kling et al, 2008; Duggan and Scott Morton,
2008). Additionally, there remain important concerns about the high administrative costs of the
program and about plans’ ability to cream-skim (or avoid) certain types of patients. Thus while
Medicare Part D has certainly been more of a success than its most vocal opponents predicted,
there is still substantial room for improvement.
Sponsors of Medicare Part D
A variety of organizations can sponsor Medicare Part D plans: insurance companies,
employers, union organizations, Medicare managed care plans, and others. Plan sponsors offer
one of two broad types of private plans: stand-alone prescription drug plans that supplement fee-
for-service Medicare, and Medicare Advantage prescription drug plans, in which the drug plan is
integrated into the overall health care provided by a managed care organization.2 Medicare
Advantage plans existed well before the creation of Part D—and in fact some were already
providing prescription drug coverage in 2003. Prescription drug plans are specific to a region
and must be available to a consumer anywhere in the region. There are 34 stand-alone
prescription drug plan regions and 26 Medicare Advantage drug plan regions nationwide
(excluding the territories). Medicare Advantage plans generally define their own service areas
offered at a local (county) level rather than a regional level.
In this article, we focus primarily on stand-alone prescription drug plans. One reason is
that significantly more Medicare recipients are enrolled in them: of the 57 percent of Medicare
recipients enrolled in Part D as of June 2008, more than two-thirds chose stand-alone
prescription drug plans. In addition, Medicare Advantage plans are purposefully subsidized
more heavily to encourage more Medicare recipients to enroll in the managed form of the
benefit. Taking these factors together with the manner in which Medicare Advantage combines
the drug benefit and a menu of other medical services, quick comparisons of a prescription drug
plan to a Medicare Advantage plan are not especially fruitful.
Sponsors of a stand-alone prescription drug plan must offer a basic plan consisting of
either the government-defined standard benefit or an alternative “actuarially equivalent” in value
(meaning that the average shares of total spending covered by the plan and the enrollee are equal
to those under the standard benefit). Sponsors can also offer enhanced plans with more
coverage, more favorable cost-sharing, a more expansive formulary (a list of drugs covered by
the plan with associated cost-sharing) —and generally higher premiums.
For 2008, there are 55 parent firms sponsoring stand-alone prescription drug plans and
1,824 region-specific plans, which works out to an average of 33 plans per firm, and 54 plans for
each of the 34 regions. This entry was much greater than the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid
Services (hereafter CMS, who administers the benefit) expected. There are no regions in the
United States with fewer than 22 basic plans offered and 47 plans overall (including Medicare
Advantage plans), which creates a large amount of choice for the typical Medicare recipient.
2 In an effort to reduce Part D’s crowding-out of private insurance coverage, the legislation also established tax-free subsidies (Medicare benefits are also tax free) to employers who provide prescription drug coverage to Medicare recipients that are at least as generous as the standard Part D plan (“creditable coverage”). The subsidy pays 28 percent of costs incurred by the employers between the deductible and an upper limit of $5,600 per enrollee in 2008, for a maximum potential subsidy of $1,491. We will have little to say about this aspect of the program.
Enrollment has been highly concentrated in a small number of plans covering large
geographic areas, with 4 percent of the 1,824 plans accounting for more than half of stand-alone
prescription drug plan enrollment in 2008. Firm concentrations are also impressive, with the top
three parent firms insuring 55 percent of total stand-alone prescription drug plan enrollees in
The Consumer’s Problem
Every year beginning on November 15, Medicare beneficiaries have the option to sign up
for Part D or to change their current plan, effective January 1 of the next calendar year. They
must remain in their chosen plans for the entire year, and cannot switch to a different plan until
the following January.3 Sponsors of prescription drug plans in each region are required to submit
all plan characteristics to CMS by the open enrollment period, so that enrollees can make
Cost-Sharing Scheme and Incentives
Part D allocates costs between the plan and the enrollee in an unusual way. Suppose that
the enrollee chooses a plan with the statutorily defined standard benefit and is ineligible for any
low-income subsidies. The enrollee pays the premium for the plan, which in 2008 equals about
$32 per month on average. An enrollee who requires medications will pay 100 percent of the
costs until spending for covered drugs reaches an initial deductible, which is $275 in 2008. After
the enrollee has paid the deductible, the next $2,235 of expenditures are paid 25 percent by the
enrollee and 75 percent by the plan until their combined spending reaches the initial coverage
limit, $2,510 in 2008. Expenditures above this level and below $5,726 fall into what has become
known as the “doughnut hole,” in which the enrollee pays 100 percent and the plan pays zero.
An enrollee who spends an average of more than $210 per month on medications will fall
into this region. These payments drive the enrollee’s out-of-pocket costs up from $834 at the
start of the doughnut hole, to a maximum of $4,050, which corresponds to $5,726 in total drug
costs. For spending above this “catastrophic threshold”, the enrollee pays the greater of 5
3 There are exceptions to this. For example, Medicare recipients residing in a nursing home or who are also eligible for Medicaid have more opportunities to change plans through special enrollment periods. Similarly, Medicare recipients who move to a different plan region can switch to a different plan around the time of their move.
percent coinsurance, or copayments of $2.25 per generic or preferred drug and $5.60 for all
others. The government pays 80 percent of the remaining costs through additional subsidies,
while the sponsor of the plan pays 15 percent and the recipient the remaining 5 percent.
It is important to emphasize that the catastrophic threshold is triggered by the enrollee’s
out-of-pocket spending and that spending on drugs not listed on the plan’s formulary is not
counted. Moreover, if an enrollee purchases an enhanced plan or additional insurance that
reduces out-of-pocket costs, she must continue cost sharing until the full out-of pocket amount of
$4,050 has been paid—regardless of total costs. In this way, Part D incentives dampen the
supply of “gap” coverage, because such coverage raises the total spending required before
reaching the catastrophic threshold, and therefore makes the enrollee more costly to the insurer.4
While the scheme described above departs from the standard intuition that it is optimal to
have steadily more cost sharing as expenditures rise, it is the natural outcome of a political
process that had three constraints. First, policymakers wanted the program to be popular with a
large fraction of Medicare recipients, even for those who spend very little on drugs. Second,
policymakers also wanted the program to have catastrophic coverage to protect those who have
high outlays from ruinous bills. Finally, the FY 2004 budget resolution capped the bill’s total
cost, and so the “doughnut hole” emerged to keep costs down.
The benefit structure laid out above is the one defined in the 2003 legislation and
followed by 24 percent of basic plans in 2008, with a market share of 17 percent overall.
However, sponsors may offer two additional types of plans, as long as projected average
payments for the enrollee are the same as would be expected under the standard plan.
The first alternative, called “actuarially equivalent coverage,” might have tiered
copayments in place of the standard 25 percent coinsurance but all other elements of the benefit
design such as the deductible and initial coverage limit would be the same as that of the standard
4 To address this issue, CMS used its demonstration authority to allow plans offering gap coverage to receive federal reinsurance in the form of extra monthly capitated payments per enrollee instead of reimbursement for specific high-cost enrollees. Indeed, the demonstration seems to be effective as the proportion of enhanced plans offering coverage in the gap rose from 36 percent in 2006 to 57 percent in 2008. For more information, see Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, “Instructions for the Part D Payment Demonstration,” May 10, 2005 (available at http://www.cms.hhs.gov/DrugCoverageClaimsData/Downloads/partdpymntdemo.pdf).
benefit. These plans comprise 26 percent of basic plans for 2008, with a market share of 23
The other alternative, called “basic alternative coverage,” may have a smaller deductible
than the standard plan or no deductible at all, as well as modified cost sharing. These plans
account for more than half of the 2008 basic offerings and have been very popular with
enrollees. Nearly two-fifths of beneficiaries enrolled in basic alternative plans in 2008 with over
half of those persons opting for zero-deductible plans. Table 2 presents the distribution of
enrollees by plan scope, benefit design, and associated design features.
When Medicare recipients compare plans, the most salient price is likely to be the
monthly premium. Premiums in 2008 range from $9.80 for the cheapest defined standard plan to
$72 and $107.50 for the most expensive basic and enhanced plans, respectively. It is important
to note that the government subsidy does not depend on the monthly premium, so as not to
distort Medicare recipients toward more generous plans.
To encourage early enrollment of healthy people, Part D imposes a permanent increase in
premiums for those who enroll later. For each month after which an enrollee is eligible for Part
D but does not sign up, she pays an additional 1 percent of the national base beneficiary premium
(defined below) for a chosen plan. Thus, for example, two years of delay would cost the enrollee
an additional 24 percent. This penalty may help to explain the popularity of plans with low
premiums, because some enrollees may not expect to need medications in the upcoming year
(see Table 3). However, by enrolling currently they can avoid the penalty on the cost of future
premiums and switch to a more generous plan later when they require medications.
Pharmacy network and plan quality
Plans vary in the pharmacy networks they offer. A “high quality” plan might have almost
every pharmacy in the region ready to dispense prescriptions. Another might limit its
distribution network to one large chain. Nearly all plans have a mail order option, and on
average plans offer lower prices for prescriptions delivered by mail.
Enrollees will also evaluate the quality of the administration of the plan. Is it easy to sign
up for? How well does it handle members’ inquiries at its call centers? Does it carry a
trustworthy brand name? At the start of the program, Medicare recipients had little information
on plan quality other than the plan sponsor’s reputation. There is some suggestive evidence that
this mattered at the start of the program: the lone national AARP plan administered by
UnitedHealth Group had the highest market share (20 percent) in 2006. But beginning with the
2008 open enrollment period, beneficiaries could access 2007 plan performance ratings via the
“Medicare Prescription Drug Plan Finder” website. The ratings cover customer service, the ease
of filling prescriptions, and the information provided on drug coverage and costs. AARP 2007
plan performance was deemed “very good” and they continued to lead the market in 2008.
Every basic Part D plan is actuarially equivalent in offering an average of $1,676 worth
of coverage along with catastrophic coverage beyond the “doughnut hole.” All else equal,
however, a plan with lower drug prices will provide more generous coverage. The drug prices
that plans set are not regulated by the government, so the price of a “covered” drug can vary
substantially across plans. A Medicare recipient can use the Medicare Plan Finder website for
this stage of the choice process. After entering a zip code, enrollees enter the list of medications
they expect to take in the coming year. The website then displays the estimated annual cost of
medications and premiums, according to the cost-sharing rules of each plan serving the region.
The cost-sharing rules matter. For example, an enrollee who takes just one inexpensive
treatment might have to pay the full cost out of pocket in a plan with a deductible, while that
enrollee might pay only a small fraction or nothing in a plan with no deductible.
Formularies and Competition among Branded Drugs
Each Part D plan has a formulary, which details the patient’s out-of-pocket cost for each
drug along with the rules the patient or physician must follow to obtain a drug. All states view a
brand-name drug and its FDA-approved generics as sufficiently close substitutes that they allow
a pharmacist to switch between the two without consulting with a physician. Insurers also view
these drugs as very close substitutes, and the formulary of virtually every plan requires—or
creates strong financial incentives for—an enrollee to purchase a generic when it is available.
A formulary also defines therapeutic submarkets. Suppose there are several patented
drugs in a therapeutic class, but no generics. These brands may be close substitutes for one
another in the sense that they ameliorate the same problem—high cholesterol, for example—but
they may differ in their side-effects or in other ways. The prescription drug plan can negotiate
with the manufacturers of drugs it considers very similar to determine which one will offer the
best deal for its enrollees. The plan is well-positioned to take the lead in such negotiations.
Patients will frequently not know enough about medicine to evaluate which drugs are appropriate
substitutes for one they are currently taking. While physicians typically know this, they are
uninformed about the prices a prescription drug plan can negotiate for each drug. Thus the plan
can evaluate tradeoffs between price and quality that neither the physician nor the Medicare
recipient can easily make. Moreover, because the plan is affecting the consumption of a large
group of consumers, it has the clout to negotiate with a drug manufacturer in a way that an
individual physician or consumer cannot.
A “three-tier” system is the most common way Part D plans organize their formulary.
Generics occupy the lowest tier and have the lowest out-of-pocket payment. “Preferred brands,”
which may have offered a price break to the plan sponsor, are on tier two with a somewhat
higher cost to the enrollee. Brands that the plan sponsor wants to discourage the use of are on
tier three and have the highest relative out-of-pocket payments. Often, there is a specialty fourth
tier containing very expensive unique and injectable drugs. Additional tools beyond price that a
formulary may use include prior authorization and step therapy. Prior authorization requires a
physician to obtain permission from the plan before prescribing the drug. Step therapy requires a
patient to try a cheaper drug and find it ineffective before moving to a more expensive one.
Lastly, a drug can simply be off the formulary; the plan does not cover it at all. The purpose of
these rules and price differences is to drive demand toward drugs on the lowest possible tier, as
To develop a sense of how choices between brand-name drugs with different formulary
placement might play out, we analyzed three prominent 2007 stand-alone prescription drug plans
in California: the AARP MedicareRX Saver plan from UnitedHealth Group, the WellCare
Signature Basic Alternative plan, and the Sierra Rx Basic Alternative plan, which had 21, 9, and
8 percent of the regional market, respectively. We focused on the 20 top-selling brand-name,
cholesterol-reducing drugs known as statins and established whether they were preferred, non-
preferred, or off-formulary in these three plans.5 The formulary status and the prices of each drug
vary substantially across plans. In the AARP plan, for example, five of the 20 drugs were
preferred, eight were non-preferred, and the other seven were off-formulary. In the WellCare
plan, three were preferred, one non-preferred, and 16 off-formulary. In the Sierra plan, four were
preferred, and 16 were off-formulary. Pricing was consistent with formulary placement, that is,
drugs on lower tiers relative to the other plans were cheaper. There was little overlap between
these plans in formulary placement; for example, only one drug (Zetia) was on the preferred tier
in all three plans. This latter finding suggests that statin manufacturers were selective in
providing discounts to these plans in exchange for better (or exclusive) formulary placement.
Tiered cost-sharing may not change the total number of prescriptions filled, but drives
demand toward generic and preferred brand drugs. The ability to move market share between
therapeutic substitutes that have market power (i.e. patent protection) allows plans to obtain
discounts, reducing the cost per branded prescription. This mechanism may also allow the plan
to benefit consumers by “guiding” them to cheaper, therapeutically-equivalent drugs.
Clearly, each Medicare recipient faces a complex task in choosing a prescription drug
plan. The factors that she is likely to consider include the expected out-of-pocket cost of each
plan, the breadth of each plan’s formulary, and the reputation of the plan sponsor. The
dimensionality of the choice problem rises according to the number of drugs used—the average
elderly person uses five different prescription drugs (Neuman et al., 2007). Moreover, a
forward-looking enrollee would not only consider the coverage of drugs currently consumed, but
also the plan’s formulary breadth given the risk of an adverse health shock in the future that
could lead to additional drugs required.6 The expected value of a plan’s formulary breadth is a
difficult calculation to perform, however, as it requires knowledge of many drug prices, their
associated cost-sharing, the likelihood of different types of health shocks, and the likely
effectiveness of each drug for each health shock.
5 This kind of information is readily available from the Medicare.gov “Plan Finder” website. We collected this data in May 2007. In order of 2006 sales rank according to the market research firm IMS, the 20 drugs we looked at are Lipitor, Zocor, Zetia, Crestor, Tricor, Pravachol, Niaspan ER, Lescol XL, Welchol, Lescol, Altoprev ER, Antara, Colestid, Triglide, Lofibra, Mevacor, Lopid, Questran, Prevalite. Questran Light.
6 Recent research by Domino et al (2008) indicates that there is considerable switching of drugs among Medicare recipients and thus focusing only on drugs currently consumed leads to suboptimal choices.
Behavioral economics research documents that a complicated choice environment, such
as Part D, can easily overwhelm the typical consumer.7 Frank and Newhouse (2007) believe this
complexity has discouraged enrollment and likely led to sub-optimal choices that are not cost
effective, especially among poor and less-educated beneficiaries and those with cognitive
impairments. Indeed, 10 percent of eligible beneficiaries both failed to enroll in any Part D plan
and had no other source of prescription drug coverage in 2008, with a recent study suggesting
that most of this group would benefit from enrolling in Part D (Heiss, McFadden, and Winter,
2007). Moreover, a recent experimental study by Kling et al (2008) finds a significant increase
in plan switching when Part D recipients are provided with personalized information on the cost
of alternative plans. Because this information was already publicly available, these findings
suggest that many Medicare recipients are not obtaining the information that they need to make
The Sponsor’s Problem
Medicare Part D is a complicated and ambitious program that was designed to promote
competition between private insurers in the delivery of a prescription drug benefit while
simultaneously addressing the problems of moral hazard and adverse selection that affect the
equity and efficiency of most social insurance programs. To reduce moral hazard, the program
seeks to have enrollees face the true marginal cost8 of the differences in prices between these
prescription drug plans—while subsidizing the insurance purchases of enrollees at the same time.
To reduce plans’ incentives to select the most profitable (i.e. least costly) Medicare recipients,
Part D provides additional subsidies for those recipients with high expected costs and with high
actual costs. In this section, we discuss more specifically how Part D influences firm incentives.
From the Bid to the Monthly Premium
Firms interested in sponsoring a stand-alone prescription drug plan must first decide
which of the 34 regions to serve. They must then submit a“bid” to CMS, which represents the
7 See for example an experimental study by Choi, Laibson, and Martin (2007), who find that individuals did not minimize mutual fund administrative costs, even though it was in their interest to do so. On the other hand, recent research by Aguiar and Hurst (2005) indicates that after retirement individuals have more time than other adults to spend on cost-reducing search. Thus, many Medicare recipients may have sufficient time to shop for a Part D plan. 8 Of course, part of the variation in premiums across plans will reflect the composition of enrollees.
amount of revenue the plan expects to need to provide a typical Part D enrollee with basic
coverage after subtracting expected cost-sharing payments by enrollees and government
catastrophic and low-income subsidies. This revenue will cover drug costs, administrative costs,
and a desired profit margin. The sponsor of an enhanced plan must submit a bid that covers only
the costs of running the “basic” aspects of the plan, and not the costs of the enhanced features.
The federal government is permitted to review each bid to ensure it is reasonable and negotiate
with the plan sponsor if deemed otherwise.
There are a number of steps from the plan bid to the calculation of the actual monthly
premium. Once all bids are approved, CMS calculates a “national average bid,” weighted by
each plan’s share of the total population enrolled in Part D. Bids were equally weighted in the
first year of the program. A blended method was adopted in 2007 and 2008, however, as a
statutorily-defined calculation would have a produced a national average bid in these years well
below the 2006 level and thus substantially lower subsidies and higher premiums on average.
CMS then multiplies this national average bid by a certain percentage (34.7 percent in
2008) that is determined each year to arrive at the “base beneficiary premium.”9 In 2008 the
national average bid and the base beneficiary premium were $80.52 and $27.93 per month,
respectively. This base beneficiary premium is then modified to obtain the actual amount that
enrollees pay each month. If a plan had bid $100.52—that is, $20 more than the average plan—
its actual monthly premium would be $20 more than the basic premium, or $47.93. Likewise, if
a plan bid $20 below the average, the premium for that plan would be only $7.93 (premiums
cannot fall below zero). This causes the enrollee to bear the full cost on the margin of selecting a
more or less generous plan, which is an important design feature of Part D.
A firm does not have the incentive to place a bid below its expected costs, because it will
be reimbursed from all sources only up to its bid. Thus, underbidding will simply cause the plan
to lose money that year. Conversely, a bid above costs will earn the plan a higher profit margin
per enrollee, but it risks losing market share due to its higher premium.
Policies to minimize risk selection 9 The Part D legislation requires that program costs for Medicare recipients with no low-income subsidy be subsidized 74.5 percent by the federal government, with 25.5 percent paid by enrollees who do not qualify for low-income subsidies. Since most costs above the catastrophic threshold are covered by federal subsidies, enrollees are responsible for a greater percentage of the bid amount in order to pay 25.5 percent of total costs.
When designing Medicare Part D, policymakers knew that the program would be
unlikely to succeed if competition among insurers revolved around attracting healthy, and
avoiding costly, enrollees. Relative to all recipients in Part D, those with three or more chronic
conditions consume 25 percent more prescription drugs and are 40 percent more likely to spend
over $300 per month procuring them (Neuman et al., 2007). This high concentration of outlays
means that a plan sponsor’s return to achieving a favorable risk profile is significant. Thus, CMS
incorporated various policies to reduce the returns to such socially wasteful competition.
One of the most important policies for harnessing competition among Part D plans is risk
adjustment. The Part D risk adjustment system adjusts plan payments for each enrollee by the
expected variation in prescription drug spending, using a combination of demographic and health
risk factors. Specifically, the system takes into account the enrollee’s age, sex, low-income
subsidy eligibility, institutional status (for example, living in a nursing home), and health status.
Health is scored by counting the disease categories the enrollee falls into (based on other
Medicare claims) such as diabetes, heart disease, or arthritis. Each characteristic is scored a
number of points and a total is created for the enrollee, with higher points measuring higher
projected costs. Some points are additive (like those for diseases) and some multiplicative (for
example, being eligible for a low-income subsidy multiplies the point total by 1.08).
Table 4 illustrates the risk adjustment calculation for a hypothetical 75 year-old woman
with diabetes and hypertension who is eligible for full Medicaid benefits, using the factors in
effect for 2006 (CMS, 2005; adapted from Merlis, 2007). The age/sex and disease factors are
aggregated to give a preliminary risk factor of 0.8466, which is then multiplied by the low-
income factor for full-benefit Medicaid eligibles (1.08) to result in a final risk factor of 0.9143.
The net government subsidy is the bid times the risk adjustment factor less the premium the
enrollee pays. Notice that each enrollee pays a premium that is not adjusted for her own risk.
After this process, the plan’s bid should reflect its expected cost of an enrollee with a risk factor
of 1.000, thereby protecting it from the need to calculate the distributions of risk in the
population or forecasting what distribution it might draw.
The success of the risk adjustment system depends on its ability to capture enough of the
predictable variation in per-enrollee outlays through adjustment of the federal subsidy to make
expenditures on risk selection unprofitable. Currently, the system offsets approximately one-
quarter of the variance in drug spending per year among the elderly, but could offset at least half
if past drug usage were included in the formula (Wrobel et al., 2003-2004). This limited risk
adjustment is a weakness in Part D. After the first year of operation, prescription drug plans
presumably knew more than the government about expected costs for their enrollees. As more
data accumulates, some plans may attempt to select enrollees advantageously. Government
statisticians who create the risk factors will try to keep up—but the plans will have better data.
Another important way in which Part D reduces plans’ incentives to select the healthiest
patients is through an 80 percent subsidy for all costs above the catastrophic threshold, which
will reduce the costs to the plan of enrolling an especially sick beneficiary.
Risks of participating in a new industry
Plan sponsors faced considerable business risk in the first few years of Part D given the
complexity of the program and the difficulty in forecasting the number and the average
characteristics of their enrollees. To address this issue, the federal government shares in each
plan’s overall profits or losses if they fall outside of specific “risk corridors.”
To determine this, CMS first calculates a target drug expenditure for each plan, equal to
the sum of federal subsidies and enrollee premiums less administrative costs. If the plan’s total
spending for standard drug benefits diverges from the target by 5 percent or more, the
government shares the loss or gain. In the case of a 5 to 10 percent deviation, CMS pays half of
the loss or recoups half of the gain. If the difference is more than 10 percent, Medicare absorbs
Prescription drug plans are also allowed to develop a specialty tier containing very
expensive unique and injectable drugs, such as genomic and biotech products, with the freedom
to exempt these drugs from the normal rules governing formulary tier exceptions and to maintain
high cost sharing at or actuarially equal to 25 percent coinsurance before the initial coverage
limit. By mandating a sustained contribution rate by the enrollee, this decision protects plans
from the risk of bearing a significant share of specialty drug spending.
With these rules in place, Part D plans currently face limited uncertainty about their costs.
The government both insures plans (80 percent) for the risk that certain individuals are very
expensive to insure and for the aggregate risk that their populations are expensive to insure (80
percent). These rules have helped to encourage private-sector participation in the early years of
the plan. However, while both types of subsidies reduce plan risk, they also reduce incentives to
Can Part D Plans Influence Pharmaceutical Prices?
The designers of Part D hoped that competition would hold down the program costs: in
particular, they envisioned an intertwined pattern of competition involving both drug
manufacturers and insurance plans. One important dimension of this was competition between
drug manufacturers for preferred placement of its products on each plans’ formularies. Typically,
whichever drug manufacturer—out of those producing therapeutic substitutes—offers the lowest
(quality-adjusted) price to an insurance plan gets preferential placement for its product, while its
competitors lose sales. Manufacturers can offer discounts for particular formulary placement
(preferred tier) or exclusive formulary placement (only statin on preferred tier). Manufacturers
can also offer greater discounts for higher realized market share: for example, the manufacturer
could offer an additional 10 percent price reduction for 40 percent market share in the class.
Designing incentives and procedures that allow the plan to move market share in a way
that is acceptable to enrollees and physicians is a valuable skill for a prescription drug plan. The
more effectively a plan moves market share for favored products—either due to formulary
design, utilization management techniques, bigger differences between preferred and non-
preferred brands, better rules for usage of expensive drugs, or other rules—the lower its
acquisition cost of drugs is likely to be relative to other plans.
However, moving market share is difficult for a prescription drug plan. After all,
physicians typically see dozens of patients who belong to many different plans, and the
physicians cannot possibly keep track of all the associated formularies. For this reason, the plans
typically focus on providing incentives to the patient and the pharmacist. The hope is that a
patient taking a non-preferred drug might ask her physician about alternative drugs that are less
expensive, or the pharmacist might suggest alternatives since he can see the formulary rules and
understands both prices and substitutability. The plan might additionally ensure the pharmacy
earns a higher profit from the preferred drug.
Recent research suggests that Part D consumers are likely to respond to demand-side
policies to move market share. Chandra, Gruber, and McKnight (2007) analyzed a policy
change that raised cost sharing for retired public employees in California and found the sample
population to be quite price elastic in their demand for all types of drugs, including those that
control acute life-threatening and chronic conditions. The implied price elasticities appear to
greatly exceed those observed in the famous RAND Health Insurance Experiment, suggesting
that prescription drug plans could steer their enrollees’ demand through financial incentives.
Duggan and Scott Morton (2008) examine the question of whether the prescription drug
plans are elastic demanders by analyzing national price and quantity data for a sample of more
than 500 large-sales branded drugs that have varying levels of sales to elderly Americans. The
paper exploits variation across drugs in the pre-Part D “Medicare market share” to investigate the
effect of the program on the average price and utilization of branded treatments. They find that
Part D caused a significant decline in average pharmaceutical prices, relative to the market trend.
The magnitude of the effect is substantial, with a lower bound of 13 percent. This result suggests
that moving consumers from standard cash-paying status into a prescription drug plan with an
active formulary has an economically meaningful impact on drug prices.
When There are Fewer Therapeutic Substitutes
A prescription drug plan has the most leverage to steer demand toward products on which
price concessions are offered when there is potential competition. However, the first drugs to be
developed in a new class of drugs that offer unique therapeutic advantages for elderly users may
present a financial problem for Part D. The monopoly power this type of drug enjoys, combined
with insurance that covers a high percentage of the consumer’s cost, means that manufacturers of
such products are in a position to set a price higher than a monopolist selling to an uninsured
market, and still sell the same quantity (Frank and Newhouse, 2007). This feature of Part D is
likely to receive scrutiny if, when the next breakthrough drug arrives on the market, its price is
high. Prescription drug plans may then be required to place it on their formularies and set a co-
payment. A similar problem is present if there are just one or two treatments in an existing class
given that plans would usually be required to include both on their formularies.
A second issue is that the CMS requires plans to cover at least two drugs in every
therapeutic class and “all or substantially all” drugs in six “protected classes.”10 These protected
10 The two-drug requirement does not apply when only one drug is available for a particular category or class, or when only two drugs are available and one is clinically superior. “Substantially all” means that all drugs in the protected classes are expected to be included in plan formularies, with exceptions for multi-source brands of
classes are immunosuppressants, antidepressants, antipsychotics, anticonvulsants, HIV
antiretrovirals, and antineoplastics (cancer). Moreover, plans cannot use utilization management
techniques (like requirements for prior authorization or step therapy) on beneficiaries stabilized
on a drug regimen in one or more of these six categories prior to enrollment in Part D, unless
they can demonstrate extraordinary circumstances. Plans may however, use these techniques to
manage therapy for beneficiaries who begin treatment with drugs in these categories other than
antiretrovirals. By removing the ability to exclude or manage certain drugs, these rules remove
some of the plan’s ability to shift market share and therefore obtain low prices. Additionally,
loosely speaking, drugs in these six categories tend to be weaker substitutes for one another than
the “average” drug. For example, a person often develops resistance to an HIV drug over time,
and some tumors respond to some chemotherapy drugs and not others. Thus, we might expect
that the prescription drug plan will be less able to use its tools to obtain low prices in these
Duggan and Scott Morton (2008) shed some light on this potential problem also. They
find that brands with few therapeutic substitutes and high sales to Part D eligibles do not
experience the price decline relative to trend evidenced by drugs with several substitutes,
indicating that the role of a plan’s formulary in stimulating competition and lowering prices is
important. One might expect the same pattern for protected classes given that all drugs in these
categories must be covered, and indeed the authors’ estimates are qualitatively similar but
Copayments will differ substantially across plans both for long-term maintenance drugs
and for curative, acute-care drugs, as will be discussed below. Consumers can easily search for
the lowest out-of-pocket cost plan that offers a particular set of drugs by using the Plan Finder,
whereas many acute drugs are consumed with little advance warning. Thus, we might expect
that prescription drug plans work harder to obtain low prices on maintenance medications than
others. There is currently little evidence on this point for Part D plans, though previous evidence
on retail price dispersion across pharmacies is consistent with this (Sorenson, 2000).
identical molecular structure, extended release products when an immediate-release product is included, products that have the same active ingredient, and dosage forms that do not provide a unique route of administration.
To investigate this issue, we collected evidence on a sample of 821 drugs in the
California region in May 2007, using the Plan Finder website: 569 brand-name and 253 generic.
The sample included the top-selling drugs in therapeutic categories with a high concentration of
spending by the elderly, based on the 2004 Medical Expenditure Panel Survey. We collected
evidence on both acute-care and maintenance drugs. We found that for brand-name drugs, the
average price of acute-care drugs from the preferred network pharmacy was $491, while the
average price of maintenance drugs was $114. However, when looking at generic drugs,
essentially no price difference existed between acute-care and maintenance drugs. Of course,
this finding is far from conclusive, as it could be driven by the nature of the classes of drugs in
each group. This question remains an important area for future research.
Enrollees without financial incentives
Prescription drug plans serve many enrollees for whom it is difficult to provide incentives
to move market share. Medicare Part D replaced Medicaid as the primary source of prescription
drug coverage for enrollees eligible for both programs, individuals known as dual eligibles.
“Duals” are eligible for Medicare because they are elderly or on the Social Security Disability
Insurance program, and eligible for Medicaid because they are sufficiently poor. Table 5
provides enrollment information for Medicare beneficiaries with prescription drug coverage,
including information on insurance from other sources. Unless a Medicare recipient who was
also eligible for Medicaid made an active choice, she was randomly assigned to one of the low-
cost plans in the relevant region. The premium paid by the dual eligible would be zero for any
plan with a premium at or below the enrollment-weighted regional average. If she wanted to
choose a more expensive plan, the enrollee would pay the difference between that plan’s
premium and the regional average premium.
Beneficiaries with incomes below 150 percent of poverty ($15,600 for individuals;
$21,000 for couples in 2008) and modest assets ($11,990 for individuals; $23,970 for couples)
receive assistance in several ways. All recipients of the low-income subsidy have a zero or
reduced deductible and face smaller co-payments or coinsurance. Moreover, there is no
coverage gap; instead, enrollees continue with cost sharing until they reach the out-of-pocket
threshold. “Full subsidy” enrollees, including duals, pay no premium, have very low co-
payments for drugs below the catastrophic threshold ($1.05 for generics or preferred drugs or $3
all others), and nothing for expenditures above the catastrophic threshold. “Partial subsidy”
enrollees face standard cost-sharing during catastrophic coverage and a reduced premium phased
out on a sliding scale basis. Dual eligibles account for half of those eligible for the low-income
subsidy and one-fourth of all beneficiaries enrolled in Part D.
Since Part D enrollees with low-income subsidies pay little or no cost sharing, their
utilization cannot easily be controlled through demand-side financial incentives. Instead, plans
might seek to influence their choices through requirements for prior authorization for certain
drugs, step therapy, or a more restrictive formulary.
How Subsidies Reduce Incentives to Create Competition
Dual-eligibles are on average in worse health and thus more expensive to insure
compared to the average Medicare recipient. They are also more likely to suffer from cognitive
impairment and psychoses, and they have higher rates of significant chronic illnesses such as
HIV/AIDS, diabetes, pulmonary disease, stroke, and Alzheimer’s. Total health care spending—
which includes Medicare, Medicaid, supplemental insurance and out-of-pocket spending across
all payers—for duals averaged about $23,543 per person in 2004, more than twice the amount
for all other Medicare beneficiaries (Med PAC, 2007a).
Recall that a prescription drug plan is subsidized 80 percent for expenditures on enrollees
who exceed the catastrophic threshold. The high rates of subsidy for the plan significantly
dampen the plan’s incentives to put maximal pricing pressure on manufacturers, given that each
additional dollar of spending is paid primarily by Medicare, not the plan or the patient. This
illustrates the tradeoff between reducing the incentive to select healthy patients (adverse
selection) and increasing the incentive to seek low prices (cost containment).
Issues Going Forward
The role of adverse selection in Medicare Part D is complex because of the variety of
subsidies plans receive for the very sick. But broadly speaking, any plan offering more generous
coverage is at risk of attracting the sicker enrollees, who will tend to be unprofitable. For
example, it was widely reported that enhanced plans that offered brand coverage in the doughnut
hole in 2006 attracted expensive enrollees, and virtually all eliminated that feature for 2008
(Alonso-Zaldivar, 2006). On the other hand, a plan that enrolls Medicare recipients with
expenditures below the deductible or with relatively low spending and charges these recipients a
One way for plans to attract healthier patients is to select their formularies with care. For
example, if plans were allowed to restrict their coverage in classes of drugs differentially
consumed by high-cost beneficiaries, they could use this tool to “cream-skim” a relatively high
number of low-cost patients. However, one study of 2006 plan formularies did not find a pattern
of more restrictive coverage in plans for which those with low-income subsidies were eligible.
Indeed, the median number of drugs listed by plans available to those with low-income subsidies
was slightly greater than that for basic plans overall (Med PAC, 2007a). Another study of plan
formularies available to those with low-income subsidies in three prescription drug plan regions
found the least generous formulary covers between 72 and 77 of the top 100 most commonly
used drugs by duals, while the median plan covers just over 90 drugs, with the vast majority
placed on preferred tiers (Med PAC, 2007b). Moreover, plans have not been complaining about
how expensive the dual population is to cover, which leads us to believe that the government
subsidy is causing duals to be either neutral or profitable for plans. Based on this limited
evidence from the first few years of the program, we are temporarily concluding that the adverse
selection issue appears not to be a significant problem at present.
Of course, one powerful reason why formularies are not being manipulated in this way
may be the government oversight of formulary choices. The government imposes minimum
formulary requirements and also provides a safe harbor for plans that utilize a therapeutic
classification system consistent with guidelines published by the United States Pharmacopeia
(the independent organization which serves as the official agency for setting standards on quality
and classification of drug products). In addition, CMS has the authority to review the specific
drugs, tiering, and utilization management strategies employed in each Part D plan formulary to
ensure that they that they are not designed to drive away enrollees with particular conditions.
The current structure of Part D will likely perpetuate the need for continued scrutiny of
plan formularies. Even if CMS designs a risk adjustment system that more accurately predicts
costs, it cannot totally eliminate the incentives of prescription drug plans to design their
formularies to discourage enrollment of beneficiaries with high expected levels of prescription
drug spending or encourage plan termination by enrollees with high actual costs.
A Handout for the Drug Companies?
Given that Part D is now subsidizing the cost of medications for Medicare recipients by
75 percent, it is perhaps not surprising that utilization of drugs in this group has increased. For
example, Lichtenberg and Sun (2007) and Yin et al (2007) investigate the effect of Part D on out
of pocket costs and utilization with data on prescriptions filled by Walgreens during the period
from late 2004 to early 2007. Both studies estimate that Part D reduced the out of pocket costs
of drugs consumed by the elderly and led to a sizeable increase in utilization.
A 2007 analysis commissioned by Pharma (2007) looked at the impact of Part D on
patient out-of-pocket costs and utilization for the previously uninsured. For this study,
Verispan’s pharmacy transaction records were obtained for all patients age 65 and older for the
period January 1, 2005 through December 31, 2006. The study found that the average number of
prescriptions filled each month for the previously uninsured almost doubled, with patients
eligible for low-income subsidies experiencing larger increases. Out-of-pocket cost savings were
also sizeable, with the cost per day of supply falling by 69 percent.
In combination with the finding of lower prices in Duggan and Scott Morton (2008), this
suggests Part D is providing more drugs at lower prices to Medicare recipients. Since the
marginal costs of drugs are very low, this is in certain respects a socially efficient change.11 In
any case, it appears that at least in 2006 and 2007, concerns about the Part D program being
mainly a handout to the pharmaceutical industry have not been realized.
From a broader point of view, the issue is not only how Part D affects drug spending, but
also how it affects overall health care spending. Because stand-alone prescription drug plans are
not vertically-integrated health care providers like the Medicare Advantage plans described
above, inefficient treatment patterns that save on drug costs but increase other health care costs
might be encouraged by the stand-alone plans (Goldman and Joyce, 2008). In contrast, a
Medicare Advantage drug plan would be willing to spend more on the pharmacy benefit if it
reduced subsequent medical costs by more. Therefore, a stand-alone prescription drug plan may
be a less efficient way to deliver a pharmacy benefit when considering health care costs as a
whole. This issue offers an important direction for future research.
11 Of course, a full welfare calculation would need to account for the deadweight loss associated with the tax revenue raised and the effect on firms’ innovation incentives.
The results from recent research suggest that most of the 4.6 million Medicare recipients
without prescription drug coverage would benefit from enrolling in Part D (Heiss et al, 2007).
The complexity of the program is one possible reason that these individuals are choosing not to
enroll. Research by these same authors and by Kling et al (2008) further indicates that relatively
many Part D recipients are making sub-optimal plan choices, causing them to spend more out of
pocket than is necessary. The complexity of the choice problem they face could be driving these
poor choices, which strongly suggests that simplification of the choice-set and increased
outreach to Medicare recipients by CMS and other organizations would save Medicare recipients
Even without more outreach, it seems plausible that Medicare recipients will make better
choices as they accumulate more experience with Part D. For example, in the first year of the
program, the Kling study found that Medicare recipients paid much more attention to the
monthly premium than to the (less transparent) out-of-pocket costs for their current and potential
future drugs. A year or two of experience with Part D may increase the salience of the cost-
sharing arrangements for each drug and allow Medicare recipients both to reduce their out-of-
pocket expenditures and to choose a formulary more tailored to their own health care needs.
Even prior to the enactment of Medicare Part D, federal spending on health care was
increasing significantly more rapidly than GDP and was creating a strain on the federal budget.
For example, from 2000 to 2005, inflation-adjusted spending by the federal government on
Medicare increased by 5.5 percent per year versus real GDP growth of just 2.1 percent per year.
This difference accelerated in 2006 with the introduction of Part D, with Medicare spending
increasing by 17.3 percent in just one year to reach $360 billion (SSA, 2007). The
Congressional Budget Office forecasts that Medicare spending as a fraction of GDP will more
than double in the next two decades, as per capita health care costs continue to increase and the
baby boom generation ages. This expenditure growth will arguably represent the most important
challenge in domestic policy-making in the decades ahead. Thus while the addition of Part D
may have improved the quality of health care for Medicare recipients, it has substantially
worsened the outlook for the federal budget.
Conclusion
We view the first two and a half years of operation for Medicare Part D as relatively
successful overall, given the challenges involved. The market for Part D plans has spawned
many options for consumers and the fraction of Medicare recipients with prescription drug
coverage has increased substantially. Competition among plans is driving premiums down to
levels lower-than-anticipated by policy-makers and sponsors. The prices that plans pay to
manufacturers for branded drugs are on average lower than the prices the manufacturers were
receiving before the program and utilization of these treatments has increased.
However, there remain important concerns about the program going forward. Recent
research strongly suggests that many Medicare recipients are making sub-optimal choices, either
by not enrolling in Part D or by choosing a sub-optimal plan. Additionally, while the program
has on average reduced pharmaceutical prices, it has if anything increased prices for treatments
without good substitutes. A third concern is that, as plans accumulate more information on
utilization by their own enrollees, they may shift their formularies to discourage re-enrollment by
the least profitable patients. The creation of this program has substantially worsened the long-
term fiscal outlook for the federal government, with overall Medicare spending approximately
ten percent greater overall than it would be without Part D. Finally, the administrative expenses
(including sales costs and plan profits) of the Part D program are almost six times higher than the
administrative expenses of traditional Medicare, so this program is very expensive to administer
(Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, 2007).
A number of questions about Part D remain unanswered and represent important topics
for future research. Perhaps most importantly, there is scant evidence regarding the effect of Part
D on the health or medical expenditure risk of Medicare recipients. Additionally, more evidence
is needed regarding the determinants of Part D enrollment and the selection of a Part D plan. Is
the complexity of Part D the main reason for the sub-optimal choices or are there other reasons
as well? This information would be useful to policymakers as they consider which interventions
to launch to help Medicare recipients optimize in this complicated choice environment.
References
Aguiar, Mark & Erik Hurst, “Consumption versus Expenditure,” Journal of Political Economy, 2005; 113(5), 919-948. Alonso-Zaldivar, Ricardo, “The Nation; Insurer scales back, widening Medicare prescription gap; The Humana plan, used by many seniors to bridge the ‘doughnut hole,’ will no longer pay for brand-name drugs” Los Angeles Times, 29 November 2006: A31. Board of Trustees, 2008 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Funds, March 2008. Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS), “Part D Payment and Risk Adjustment, Final Part D Risk Adjustment Model,” April 2005. At <www.cms.hhs.gov/DrugCoverageClaimsData/02_RxClaims_PaymentRiskAdjustment.asp>. Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS), “2008 Enrollment Information, Total Medicare Beneficiaries with Prescription Drug Coverage,” January 2008a. Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS), “National Health Expenditure Data,” May 2008b. At <http://www.cms.hhs.gov/nationalhealthexpenddata>. Chandra, Amitabh, Jonathan Gruber, and Robin McKnight, “Patient Cost-Sharing, Hospitalization Offsets, and the Design of Optimal Health Insurance for the Elderly,” NBER Working Paper No. 12972, March 2007. Choi, James, David Laibson, and Brigitte Madrian. “Why Does the Law of One Price Fail?” Harvard University mimeo, 2007. Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, Majority Staff, “Private Medicare Drug Plans: High Expenses and Low Rebates Increase the Costs of Medicare Drug Coverage,” United States House of Representatives, October 2007. Congressional Budget Office (CBO), “A Detailed Description of CBO’s Cost Estimate for the Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit,” July 2004. Congressional Budget Office (CBO), “Accounting for Sources of Projected Growth in Federal Spending on Medicare and Medicaid,” Economic and Budget Issue Brief, May 2008. Domino, Marisa et al., “Why Using Current Medications to Select a Medicare Part D Plan May Lead to Higher Out-of-Pocket Payments,” Medical Care Research and Review, February 2008; 65(1): 114-26. Duggan, Mark and Fiona Scott Morton. “The Distortionary Effects of Government Procurement: Evidence for Medicaid Prescription Drug Purchasing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 2006; 121(1), 1-30.
Duggan, Mark and Fiona Scott Morton, “The Effect of Medicare Part D on Pharmaceutical Prices and Utilization,” NBER Working Paper No. 13917, April 2008. Frank, Richard and Joseph Newhouse, “Mending the Medicare Drug Benefit: Improving Consumer Choices and Restructuring Purchasing,” The Brookings Institution, Hamilton Project Discussion Paper 2007-03, April 2007. Goldman, Dana and Geoffrey Joyce, “Medicare Part D: A Successful Start with Room for Improvement,” Journal of the American Medical Association, April 2008; 299(16): 1954–55. Grabowski, Henry, and C. Daniel Mullins, “Pharmacy Benefit Management, Cost-Effectiveness Analysis and Drug Formulary Decisions,” Social Science and Medicine 1997; 45(4): 535–44. Heiss, Florian, Daniel McFadden, and Joachim Winter, “Mind the Gap! Consumer Perceptions and Choices of Medicare Part D Prescription Drug Plans,” NBER Working Paper No. 13627, November 2007. Hoadley, Jack. “Medicare Part D: Simplifying the Program and Improving the Value of Information for Beneficiaries,” Commonwealth Fund Issue Brief, May 2008. Kling, Jeffery et al., “Misperception in Choosing Medicare Drug Plans,” Unpublished manuscript, June 2008. Lichtenberg, Frank and Shawn Sun, “The Impact of Part D on Prescription Drug Use By The Elderly” Health Affairs, November/December 2007; 26(6): 1735–44. Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (MedPAC), A Data Book: Healthcare Spending and the Medicare Program, June 2007a. Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (MedPAC), “The Role of Beneficiary-Centered Assignment for Medicare Part D,” National Opinion Research Center / Georgetown University analysis, June 2007b. Merlis, Mark, “Medicare Payments and Beneficiary Costs for Prescription Drug Coverage,” Kaiser Family Foundation, March 2007. Neuman, Patricia et al., “Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit Progress Report: Findings From A 2006 National Survey of Seniors,” Health Affairs, September/October 2007; 26(5): w630–w643. Pharma, “Medicare Part D: Assessing the Impact for Beneficiaries without Previous Drug Coverage and Dual Eligibles,” September 2007. Sorenson, Alan, “Equilibrium Price Dispersion in Retail Markets for Prescription Drugs,” Journal of Political Economy, August 2000; 108(4): 833–50.
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, “News Release: Over 38 Million People with Medicare Now Receiving Prescription Drug Coverage,” 14 June 2006. At <www.hhs.gov/news/press/2006pres/20060614.html>. U.S. Social Security Administration. Annual Statistical Supplement. 2007. Wrobel, Marian et al. “Predictability of Prescription Drug Expenditures for Medicare Beneficiaries,” Health Care Financing Review, Winter 2003-2004; 25(2): 37–46. Yin, Wesley et al., “The Effect of the Medicare Part D Prescription Benefit on Drug Utilization and Expenditures,” Annals of Internal Medicine, February 2008; 148(3): 169-177.
Table 1. Distribution of stand-alone prescription drug plan enrollees across parent firms, 2008 Organization Enrollment Market (millions)
Note: Excludes employer-sponsored plans and union plans.
* National plans serve all 34 stand-alone prescription drug plan regions (excluding territories). Local plans serve fewer than 30 regions.
Source: Authors' calculations from CMS June 2008 Part D enrollment report, available at www.cms.hhs.gov/MCRAdvPartDEnrolData/EP. Table 2. Characteristics of 2008 stand-alone prescription drug plans Enrollment Organization* Plan type Deductible Gap coverage
Note: Excludes employer-sponsored plans and union plans.
* National plans serve all 34 PDP regions (excluding territories). Local plans serve fewer than 30 regions.
Source: Authors' calculations from CMS PDP landscape file (available at www.cms.hhs.gov/PrescriptionDrugCovGenIn) and June 2008 Part D plan enrollment report (available at www.cms.hhs.gov/MCRAdvPartDEnrolData/EP). Table 3. Average Part D premiums, Unweighted and Weighted, 2006-2008 Average premiums weighted by Average premiums unweighted enrollment All plans Basic coverage Enhanced coverage Base Beneficiary Premium
Source: Authors' calculations from CMS PDP landscape file (available at www.cms.hhs.gov/PrescriptionDrugCovGenIn) and plan enrollment reports (available at www.cms.hhs.gov/MCRAdvPartDEnrolData/EP). Table 4. Sample Risk Factor Calculation Using 2006 Factors Age/sex factor: Disease factors:
Hypertensive heart disease or hypertension
Sum of factors Final factor
Source: CMS Part D risk adjustment model (available at www.cms.hhs.gov/MedicareAdvtgSpecRateStats). Table 5. Total Medicare Beneficiaries with Prescription Drug Coverage, 2008 Beneficiaries Description (millions) Medicare Beneficiaries Eligible for Part D Medicare Part D Medicare Retiree Drug Subsidy (RDS) Other Drug Coverage
Active Workers with Medicare Secondary Payer
Other Retiree Coverage, Not Enrolled in RDS
Total Medicare Beneficiaries with Drug Coverage
* Parentheses denotes number of non-dual-eligibles receiving the low-income subsidy
^ Includes beneficiaries enrolled in other Medicare health plan types (.38 million in 2008): Local Coordinated Care plans (Health Maintenance Organizations; Point of Service plans; Preferred Provider Organizations; other Provider Sponsored Organizations); Private Fee-for-Service plans; Employer Direct Private Fee-for-Service plans; Medicare Savings Accounts; Regional Preferred Provider Organizations; and Other Health Plan Types with Prescription Drug Coverage (Demo; 1876 / 1833 Cost; Program of All Inclusive Care for the Elderly (PACE); Chronic Care Pilots)
# Includes beneficiaries with more than one of the following: TRICARE, FEHPB, VA, Active Workers
Source: CMS 2008 Enrollment Information (available at www.cms.hhs.gov/PrescriptionDrugCovGenIn).
LEY 24059 DE SEGURIDAD INTERIOR LEY Nº 24.059 Sancionada: Diciembre 18 de 1991. Promulgada: Enero 6 de 1992. El Senado y Cámara de Diputados de la Nación Argentina reunidos en Congreso, etc. sancionan con fuerza de Ley: LEY DE SEGURIDAD INTERIOR TÍTULO I PRINCIPIOS BÁSICOS Artículo 1: La presente ley establece las bases jurídicas, orgánicas y funcionales
Testimonial by Dr Anil Kumar (Swami Shantananda) M.D., D.C.H. Kriyayoga Research Institute, Jhunsi, Allahabad, U.P., India I , a U.S. citizen and a medical doctor, has specialized in the care of children and young adults for the last 38 years. After practicing modern medicine mostly in the United States of America and also in England and India, I have returned to India